26
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

Fiscal Stimulus, Fiscal Policies, and Financial Instability

Abstract:

Fiscal policies have been limited and without a capacity to generate employment as a result of the processes of financial deregulation and liberalization prior to the Global International Financial Crisis (GIFC). During the Post-crisis period, budgets were limited to face the onerous payments of the external debt service. As austerity policies deepened and job creation was set aside in order to meet the reduction in the fiscal deficit, the economy remained stable but financial instability deepened. COVID-19 highlighted the deficiencies in social spending, especially the health sector, and the lack of complementarity between monetary policy and fiscal policy in Latin American countries.

Apart from the necessity of winning the war, there is no task facing society today so important as the elimination of economic insecurity. (Lerner 1943, 38)

Hereafter, the economic and social perspectives of capitalism changed on a global scale. However, these were not far from the forecasts made by the criticism of the persistence of neoliberal policies and austerity as a way out of the issues after the Global International Financial Crisis (GIFC). The deterioration of institutions and the persistent concentration of wealth slows down the capacity of countercyclical policies and fiscal stimuli, especially in countries like those of Latin America who neither have a solid social spending policy structure nor the necessary experience of supporting institutions to hold up the generalization of full employment.

This document intends to analyze the fiscal stimulus programs and their limitations in Latin American context where debt’s burden in public spending hinders stable economic development. The COVID-19 emergency makes evident a limited public health system’s capacity, especially the imposed limitations by debt and the lack of capital control. The so-called budgetary limits, the conditions for expanding spending in some of the economies, and the social and institutional advantages of carrying out a fiscal policy without restrictions, are exposed.

The Dilemma between Monetary and Fiscal Policies

The prevalence of economic, financial, and political crises, as well as the crisis of democracies during the last fifty years, shook the economic policies exercised in the postwar period when the creation of employment and social welfare had their best years in developed countries under Keynesian thought, and in Latin America under the thought of the Prebisch of the

Comisión Económica para América Latina (CEPAL).1 The Brazilian and the Mexican miracles are two significant examples, they achieved 8% growth rates under an “import’s substitution industrialization” process despite its subsequent undermining by the monetarist counter- revolution. The influence and the imposition of orthodox policies by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), from the seventies, turned towards stabilization plans, contractionary monetary policies, and austerity, supported by coups in South America and, even after the establishment of democracy, the hegemonic thought, which has lasted over fifty years.

There has been a process of economic and financial deregulation and liberalization accompanied by the privatization of the public sector. Its basis locates with Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan, whose ideas articulate through the Washington Consensus, the Maastricht Treaty, the creation of the European Central Bank in Europe, and in underdeveloped, emerging countries such as Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico, with the Fiscal Reform. The first of the ten commandments, contemplated by said consensus, was regarding fiscal discipline: a lock on governments to avoid spending more than what was received from tax purposes (Arestis 2004). In addition to a reordering of spending priorities, where compliance with the external debt service is a priority. Financial deregulation obtained the central banks’ autonomy, whose main objective was to set inflationary goals, leaving aside the economic development. The integration of financial circuits at an international level and an invisible, progressive financial deregulation and liberalization allowed to obtain speculative profits and strengthen institutional investors, the non-financial corporate sector, parallel banking, and large commercial banks. An “irrational financial exuberance” of great profit to which the president of the Federal Reserve of the United States alluded (Greenspan 1996), evident ten years later in the “subprime crisis” and its development.

The GIFC of 2008-2009, described as the expression of the third crisis of economic thought in “The Third Crisis in Economics” by James Galbraith (2013) in the presidential address at AFEE/ASSA in 2013, referring to the lecture by Joan Robinson (1972) entitled “The Second Crisis in Economics,” was characterized as the crisis of financialization, globalization, and neoliberalism by some authors (Duménil and Levy 2011), which led to the entry of the “lender of last resort” and, as Robert Skidelsky stated in “Keynes. The Return of the Master” (Skidelsky 2010). On the contrary, procyclical support from central banks to face recession and asset depression took a 180-degree turn by deepening the austerity policies and indebtedness development of both the countries and the non-financial corporate sector. A clearly opposing idea to the Keynesian proposal, which is based on the need for public deficit spending and the complementarity between monetary and fiscal policies. Where, despite the support provided by central banks and a zero interest rate, when profit expectations are not favorable and the interest rate cannot fall any further, it is only from the impulse of public investment that marginal efficiency of capital will improve private agents’ profit expectations. The confusion regarding the monetary policy implemented “got that many economists from the mainstream thought as well as from different heterodox perspectives pronounced the dreaded words ‘SS,’ Secular Stagnation” according to Mario Seccareccia (2020).

Fiscal Policy and Financial Instability

Just as Abba Lerner (1943) mentioned: to win the war, one of the most important measures is the elimination of economic insecurity, “the central idea is that government fiscal policy, its spending and taxing, its borrowing and repayment of loans, its issue of new money and it withdrawal of money, shall all be undertaken with an eye only to the results of these actions on the economy and not to any established traditional doctrine about what is sound or unsound” (Lerner 1943, 39). For Hyman Minsky, a Big Government “to stabilize output, employment, and profits by its deficits, the lender of last resort stabilized asset values and financial markets” (Minsky 2008, 43). If Lerner and Minsky had known the macroeconomic indicators at the end of 2019 as well as the forecasts of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) at a global level, including the Latin American region, they would have been anxious to know the causes of the lack of complementarity between fiscal and monetary policies, they would also have been surprised by the development of the fall of the world’s economy from 9.5% at the end of 2020, except for China which showed a 2.3% GDP recovery (IMF 2020).

In a capitalist economy, the productive dynamics work through an overdraft, and the maintenance of zero deficit balance sheets implies limiting the credit lines of banks, companies, and households. Contrary to orthodox economic theory, it is the anticipated spending and loans that generate deposits. If the government decides to increase its expenses, companies and households will see their monetary balances increased through the sale of merchandise with which they will be able to reduce their debts through deposits. (Lavoie 2014, 196–197, 205–207) In such a way that if spending is constrained, the “vicious cycle” allows the management of liabilities and economic activity, leading to stagnation, a dynamic that Latin America has been experiencing for half a century through different stabilization and austerity plans under the thought of the IMF’s Washington Consensus.

Over half a century, Latin America has been experimenting with different stabilization and austerity plans under the Washington Consensus and the IMF. Latin America’s development from 2008–2009, and after governments whose achievements in social matters improved the population conditions by reducing the poverty indicators, reversed the decrease in poverty during the second decade of this century. There is no doubt that the pursuit of orthodox policies trying to reduce fiscal deficit laid the foundations of economic and financial fragility and instability. Therefore, the Latin American region did not achieve sustained economic growth due to a lack of fiscal policy looking to reorient public spending and achieve full employment policies. The monetarist counter-revolution focused on paying the growing external debt and on the deepening of integration into international financial markets.

The second decade of this century is a lost decade for Latin America,2 although it is unparalleled with the eighties. A decade when a Big Government was lacking and the Washington Consensus guidelines emerged along with inequalities, which resulted from income concentration in the absence of an efficient fiscal policy. To this day, Latin America faces an unprecedented historical crisis due to the impact of COVID-19 and an uncertain, unstable, and indefinite post-pandemic process in the short, medium, and long terms.

It is relevant to mention the antecedents indicated by ECLAC before the pandemic: a 0.4% economic growth performance of the GDP on average between 2014–2019. During 2019, growth came along with a reduction in foreign direct investment of 7.8%, commodities prices on average 5% below the levels of 2018. The blurring of public and private investment, coupled with a fall in exports, aggravated the growing external indebtedness. The gross public debt of the non-financial public sector represented 60.3%, and the gross public debt went from 29.8% in 2011 to 46.0% of GDP in 2019; added to this is a total gross external debt/exports of goods and services of 160.9%, which means fiscal fragility of the public finances of Latin American countries.

The priority of the region has been “to safeguard the sustainability of the public debt … a reduction of the primary deficit in Latin America, which stood at 0.6% of GDP in 2019, compared to 1.1% of the recorded GDP in 2016” (ECLAC 2020, 79). Therefore “the spending policy has focused on containing its growth, which has led to a reduction in primary spending to adjust the increasing weight of interest payments” (ECLAC 2020, 79).

For the case of Latin America, observing the development of Public Expenditure during the last decade will be enough, especially in Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico. As shown in Figure 1, the austerity policy has been imposed as one of the major burdens for Latin America so far in the twentieth century. The so-called “healthy” public finances that support the zero deficit have deteriorated the capacity of production and the well-being of the societies of the region. As Figure 1 shows, the government spending to cover Latin America’s external debt as a proportion of the GDP has exceeded the total spending for much of this century, except for the 2011 to 2014 period. However, the trend reverses during 2015, when the government’s total expense fell to $1.7 trillion, 32.9% of the GDP, and debt remained at $1.8 trillion or 36.3% of GDP.

Figure 1. Latin America: Government Spending vs. External Debt, 2000–2018

Source: Authors’ elaboration with data from CEPALSTAT and IMF, WEO, October 2020. Available at: https://bit.ly/3lpipEw and https://bit.ly/3gDthxl.

In absolute terms, the fiscal burden of total government spending was exceeded by the amount of regional external debt as of 2015 until 2018, a time when the external debt was equivalent to 2.1 trillion dollars, total public spending decreased to 1.6 trillion dollars, and only 60.5 billion allocated to social spending, that is to say, only 0.35% of the total amount. Although government investment in social spending has developed positively in recent years, considering the 19 billion dollars they presented in 2001, they are still very small amounts compared to the size of the external debt.

Fiscal Policy and Emergent Measures

The pandemic, unleashed by the SARS-CoV-2 virus, brought an unprecedented fiscal response throughout the world to provide extraordinary resources to public health systems, companies, and households in vulnerable situations. Fiscal measures reached 11.7 trillion dollars; that is, around 12% of global GDP, according to information from the International Monetary Fund (IMF 2020). Half of this figure corresponded to additional expenses or unreceived income from the waiver of tax income, while the other half came from loans and guarantees besides a liquidity injection by the public sector.

The extraordinary fiscal measures (Figure 2) have not been homogeneous since they have varied according to the country and the fiscal space available for each of them. While advanced economies (AEs) have allocated resources equivalent to a range between 10% and 12% of the GDP in additional spending and loss of income, capital, loans, and guarantees respectively, the sums in low-income developing countries (LIDCs) equals 1.8% and 0.2% of GDP. The latter means that the discretionary response capacity in fiscal terms has been proportional to the economies’ size. The higher the income, the greater the number of resources destined to alleviate the pandemic. A situation which is also evident in emerging middle-income market economies (EMMIEs), whose fiscal response in terms of GDP has oscillated between 3.7% and 2.9%.

Figure 2. Discretionary Fiscal Response to the COVID-19 Crisis in Selected Economies and Groups (Announced measures as of September, 2020, in percent of GDP)

Source: Authors’ elaboration with data from IMF Fiscal Monitor, Policies for Recovery, October 2020.

Available at: https://bit.ly/3 gDthxl

Notes: AEs = advanced economies; COVID-19 = coronavirus disease 2019; EMMIEs = emerging market and middle-income economies; LIDCs = low-income developing countries; LA = Latin America.

* Average for the five selected Latin American countries (Mexico, Colombia, Argentina, Brazil, and Chile)

**Data as of June 12, 2020

Latin America (as an average of the five major economies of the region) as part of the EMMIE countries responded with discretionary fiscal measures allocating 4.86% of GDP for additional expenses and foregone tax revenues. For capital, loans, and guarantees, the sum is equivalent to 3.04% of GDP. It is relevant to highlight the heterogeneity of the figures for the five major Latin American economies. While countries like Chile and Brazil have presented fiscal responses that range between 6.5% and 8.3% of GDP, countries like Mexico have not exceeded one percentage point of their GDP in either of the two estimated items. The case of Argentina and Colombia would be in an average situation, having allocated between 2.5% and 4% of GDP as a response in fiscal terms to alleviate the COVID-19 pandemic.3

Reflection

When reflecting upon Post-COVID-19 times, Latin American countries will face a long period of negative growth rates, massive unemployment, a digital divide that has split society, the lack of a skilled workforce, an incapable system for meeting the needs of its population, and a very unequal population pyramid. In short, the future is uncertain and, for future generations, it will be a long period where the social fabric will have to be reborn as it was after the Second World War.

The proposed monetary policies to overcome the great depression in which all the economies (except for China) have been enveloped show fifty years of mismanagement, after decades of stabilization and adjustment programs, economic and financial reforms, and several processes of financial deregulation and liberalization impacting economic and financial fragility and instability. To this is added that even the policies carried out by central banks, after the Global International Financial Crisis (GIFC) of 2007–2008, did not consider the functional policies exposed by Lerner in 1943, instead, there was an insistence on austerity policies and low-interest rates, which promoted indebtedness for non-financial corporations and an increase on sovereign debts.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Alicia Girón

Alicia Girón is Coordinator of the University Program for Asian and African Studies (PUEAA) and Researcher at the Economic Research Institute UNAM. Eugenia Correa is a member of the Postgraduate Economics Program and professor at the School of Economics UNAM. This paper is the result of the PAPIIT IN301918 Project “Financial Geography and Institutions in the World’s Economy” of the General Directorate of Academic Personnel Affairs (DGAPA-UNAM). The author is thankful to the National Council of Science and Technology (CONACyT) scholarship holders Adheli Galindo, Jairo Cisneros and Daniel Mirón, and to social service Leslie Badillo and Paola Díaz for compiling the material.

Eugenia Correa

Alicia Girón is Coordinator of the University Program for Asian and African Studies (PUEAA) and Researcher at the Economic Research Institute UNAM. Eugenia Correa is a member of the Postgraduate Economics Program and professor at the School of Economics UNAM. This paper is the result of the PAPIIT IN301918 Project “Financial Geography and Institutions in the World’s Economy” of the General Directorate of Academic Personnel Affairs (DGAPA-UNAM). The author is thankful to the National Council of Science and Technology (CONACyT) scholarship holders Adheli Galindo, Jairo Cisneros and Daniel Mirón, and to social service Leslie Badillo and Paola Díaz for compiling the material.

Notes

1 In English: Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean or ECLAC.

2 The pandemic has resulted in a 91% GDP drop of the growth rate, which means a poverty rate of up to 37.3% and an unemployment rate increase of 13.5%, evidencing a deplorable state of the systems of health and an informal economy of 158 million workers, that is, 54% of the economically active population is in informality (ECLAC 2020: 72). A higher decrease between 45% and 55% in the inflow of these capital flows due to foreign direct investment coupled with the declining trend worldwide, a drop in tourism and financial volatility which only leads to infer economic instability and financial (ECLAC 2020).

3 September 2020 data.

References

 

Related research

People also read lists articles that other readers of this article have read.

Recommended articles lists articles that we recommend and is powered by our AI driven recommendation engine.

Cited by lists all citing articles based on Crossref citations.
Articles with the Crossref icon will open in a new tab.